Call 855-808-4530 or email [email protected] to receive your discount on a new subscription.
Thank you, members of the Commission, for the honor of addressing such a distinguished and thoughtful panel. Industrial subsidies in China derive from governmental dominance of the economy and from various factors including the central, provincial and municipal governments' strategic goals, patronage, and corruption. The subsidies include direct and indirect components that affect both the top and bottom lines of industrial operations. My statement stems from research that I have conducted over the last 7 years on business in China, some of which has been published in my book, The Chinese Tao of Business: the Logic of Successful Business Strategy (John Wiley & Sons). Answers to specific concerns follow.
In what form and in what industries do subsidies exist in China?
State subsidies flow into State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs) although some well-connected private firms also benefit from indirect subsidies such as Special Market Information. In 2002, the state controlled half the industrial output and SOEs still account for 35% of urban employment. Almost all of China's heavy industry and much of its technology lies in governmental hands. The government controls about a third of China's economy through SOEs in key sectors such as defense and utilities. The State Owned Assets Supervision and Administration Committee (SASAC) directly manages the top 190 or so SOEs, the biggest of which have international stock-market listings.
Subsidies exist in all industries that the Chinese state and provincial governments considered economically or militarily strategic, including Resource Extraction, Steel, Computing, Software, R & D, Environmental Services and Conservation, and Autos.
The subsidies exist in various forms, including:
What complications, if any, in evaluating such subsidies are caused by the lack of transparency in China's government and economic systems?
Lack of transparency affects ability to monitor all forms of subsidy except perhaps Stock Listings. Opacity serves as a tax which:
Unreliability in macroeconomic data also seriously compounds the problem of estimating the effects of subsidies.
A. For example, in February 2002, the Chinese government said that China's GDP had grown by 7.3% in 2001, making it the world's fastest-growing economy. However, growth rates reported by individual provinces told another story. Only one, Yunnan, said its product had grown slower than the national rate. Taken together, the provincial figures produced a national growth rate nearly two points higher than the official rate! The National Statistics Bureau (NSB) conducts sample surveys and uses these to estimate the country's GDP and growth rate. The results have invariably disagreed with provincial figures. In 1995, the GDP growth rate suggested by provincial data averaged three percentage points higher than the figure of 10.5% produced by sample surveys. Opinions vary as regards the accuracy of the central government's estimates. However, in China, few scholars publicly attempt any detailed justification of alternative figures because of political sensitivity.
B. China's NSB also lacks the capacity to collect data outside normal information channels and lower-level officials interfere with its surveys. The numbers generated by provincial governments remain an important criterion in evaluating local officials' performance, creating an incentive for statistical falsification. The pressure to exaggerate statistics grew in the late 1990s as Chinese officials sought to pump up the economy to stave off the Asian economic slump's effects. Beijing declared that the country had to grow at least 7% a year to create jobs and to forestall social unrest. Not surprisingly, reported growth rates have not dipped below that level since.
C. Officials may also routinely underreport other sensitive data such as debt numbers, unemployment or even FDI to avoid tax payments and governmental scrutiny. The central government's methods at ascertaining the validity of data, a process it calls yasuo shuifen or 'squeezing the water', involves sample surveys, price-index adjustments and plenty of guesswork.
D. Technical difficulties, such as staff reductions among statistical analysts, have enhanced errors in data. No comprehensive measures exist for the size of the fast-growing private-business and service sectors or even for what constitutes FDI.
E. The Chinese government strictly controls economic and industrial data and even classifies some as state secrets. Routinely, Beijing has overvalued SOEs' stocks of unsold goods, and underestimated inflation. Other provinces underreport growth and activity: for example, Zhegiang province in Eastern China may have underreported growth to conceal the rapid development of private companies in its economy. Additionally, affluent provinces, such as Guangdong in Southern China, may have underreported growth to avoid paying more taxes to the central government. However, without more systematic data, economists cannot definitively state if these factors pushed up growth or even occurred.
F. Governmental officials downplay unemployment figures to mask the suffering that economic reforms and restructuring have caused. The official unemployment rate of 3.6% in 2001 excluded xiagang workers (laborers receiving small, monthly stipends from former companies and not counted as unemployed) that economists estimate to number about 10 million. The official rate also excluded farmers who left their fields to work in cities, a floating population of around 150 million unemployed migrants. Using international standards, China's unemployment rate in 2001 approximated 7.6 percent in rural areas and more than 8.5% in the cities, well above Beijing's red-flagged figure to indicate inevitable social turmoil.
G. Most disturbingly, the central government's debt numbers look highly erroneous. The Central Bank's governor, Dai Xianlong, confessed to Parliament in April 2002 that national domestic debt appeared much higher than the official numbers (16% of GDP) suggested. Dai said the figure appeared closer to 60% of GDP if one considered unfunded state-pensions' liabilities, local governments' debts, and major banks' nonperforming loans (NPLs). Dai's unusual candor may mask more bad news. Independent economists have discovered that Dai's statistics drew on China's yearbook GDP growth statistics. Debt more realistically appears closer to 100 or 125 percent of GDP. The Bank of China reported two different figures for its NPLs in 1999, one using Chinese accounting standards, another Western; the latter looms 2.6 times greater than the former. Moody's has openly called the books of China's 'Big Four' banks, 'meaningless.'
What subsidies will be utilized for the 11th Five-Year Program Period?
I anticipate that all the subsidies that I identified will continue. The 11th 5-year plan specifically identifies certain strategically important industries that will receive state subsidies. These include:
Researchers may have more difficulties monitoring the rate of subsidization as China's 11th Five-Year Plan has only two numeric targets: per capita GDP in 2010 must be double the 2000 figure and 'each work unit must cut its use of energy by 20% of current levels by 2010.' The plan fails to mention raising the price of electricity and gasoline, and unlike the previous 10 years, sets no economic growth targets.
In Part Two, Prof. Haley covers how profitable and available those subsidies are and how profitable companies are that serve the China market.
(The entire U.S.-China Commission hearing record for April 4, 2006 is available at www.uscc.gov/hearings/2006hearings/transcripts/april_4/06_04_04_trans.pdf.)
Thank you, members of the Commission, for the honor of addressing such a distinguished and thoughtful panel. Industrial subsidies in China derive from governmental dominance of the economy and from various factors including the central, provincial and municipal governments' strategic goals, patronage, and corruption. The subsidies include direct and indirect components that affect both the top and bottom lines of industrial operations. My statement stems from research that I have conducted over the last 7 years on business in China, some of which has been published in my book, The Chinese Tao of Business: the Logic of Successful Business Strategy (John Wiley & Sons). Answers to specific concerns follow.
In what form and in what industries do subsidies exist in China?
State subsidies flow into State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs) although some well-connected private firms also benefit from indirect subsidies such as Special Market Information. In 2002, the state controlled half the industrial output and SOEs still account for 35% of urban employment. Almost all of China's heavy industry and much of its technology lies in governmental hands. The government controls about a third of China's economy through SOEs in key sectors such as defense and utilities. The State Owned Assets Supervision and Administration Committee (SASAC) directly manages the top 190 or so SOEs, the biggest of which have international stock-market listings.
Subsidies exist in all industries that the Chinese state and provincial governments considered economically or militarily strategic, including Resource Extraction, Steel, Computing, Software, R & D, Environmental Services and Conservation, and Autos.
The subsidies exist in various forms, including:
What complications, if any, in evaluating such subsidies are caused by the lack of transparency in China's government and economic systems?
Lack of transparency affects ability to monitor all forms of subsidy except perhaps Stock Listings. Opacity serves as a tax which:
Unreliability in macroeconomic data also seriously compounds the problem of estimating the effects of subsidies.
A. For example, in February 2002, the Chinese government said that China's GDP had grown by 7.3% in 2001, making it the world's fastest-growing economy. However, growth rates reported by individual provinces told another story. Only one, Yunnan, said its product had grown slower than the national rate. Taken together, the provincial figures produced a national growth rate nearly two points higher than the official rate! The National Statistics Bureau (NSB) conducts sample surveys and uses these to estimate the country's GDP and growth rate. The results have invariably disagreed with provincial figures. In 1995, the GDP growth rate suggested by provincial data averaged three percentage points higher than the figure of 10.5% produced by sample surveys. Opinions vary as regards the accuracy of the central government's estimates. However, in China, few scholars publicly attempt any detailed justification of alternative figures because of political sensitivity.
B. China's NSB also lacks the capacity to collect data outside normal information channels and lower-level officials interfere with its surveys. The numbers generated by provincial governments remain an important criterion in evaluating local officials' performance, creating an incentive for statistical falsification. The pressure to exaggerate statistics grew in the late 1990s as Chinese officials sought to pump up the economy to stave off the Asian economic slump's effects. Beijing declared that the country had to grow at least 7% a year to create jobs and to forestall social unrest. Not surprisingly, reported growth rates have not dipped below that level since.
C. Officials may also routinely underreport other sensitive data such as debt numbers, unemployment or even FDI to avoid tax payments and governmental scrutiny. The central government's methods at ascertaining the validity of data, a process it calls yasuo shuifen or 'squeezing the water', involves sample surveys, price-index adjustments and plenty of guesswork.
D. Technical difficulties, such as staff reductions among statistical analysts, have enhanced errors in data. No comprehensive measures exist for the size of the fast-growing private-business and service sectors or even for what constitutes FDI.
E. The Chinese government strictly controls economic and industrial data and even classifies some as state secrets. Routinely, Beijing has overvalued SOEs' stocks of unsold goods, and underestimated inflation. Other provinces underreport growth and activity: for example, Zhegiang province in Eastern China may have underreported growth to conceal the rapid development of private companies in its economy. Additionally, affluent provinces, such as Guangdong in Southern China, may have underreported growth to avoid paying more taxes to the central government. However, without more systematic data, economists cannot definitively state if these factors pushed up growth or even occurred.
F. Governmental officials downplay unemployment figures to mask the suffering that economic reforms and restructuring have caused. The official unemployment rate of 3.6% in 2001 excluded xiagang workers (laborers receiving small, monthly stipends from former companies and not counted as unemployed) that economists estimate to number about 10 million. The official rate also excluded farmers who left their fields to work in cities, a floating population of around 150 million unemployed migrants. Using international standards, China's unemployment rate in 2001 approximated 7.6 percent in rural areas and more than 8.5% in the cities, well above Beijing's red-flagged figure to indicate inevitable social turmoil.
G. Most disturbingly, the central government's debt numbers look highly erroneous. The Central Bank's governor, Dai Xianlong, confessed to Parliament in April 2002 that national domestic debt appeared much higher than the official numbers (16% of GDP) suggested. Dai said the figure appeared closer to 60% of GDP if one considered unfunded state-pensions' liabilities, local governments' debts, and major banks' nonperforming loans (NPLs). Dai's unusual candor may mask more bad news. Independent economists have discovered that Dai's statistics drew on China's yearbook GDP growth statistics. Debt more realistically appears closer to 100 or 125 percent of GDP. The Bank of China reported two different figures for its NPLs in 1999, one using Chinese accounting standards, another Western; the latter looms 2.6 times greater than the former. Moody's has openly called the books of China's 'Big Four' banks, 'meaningless.'
What subsidies will be utilized for the 11th Five-Year Program Period?
I anticipate that all the subsidies that I identified will continue. The 11th 5-year plan specifically identifies certain strategically important industries that will receive state subsidies. These include:
Researchers may have more difficulties monitoring the rate of subsidization as China's 11th Five-Year Plan has only two numeric targets: per capita GDP in 2010 must be double the 2000 figure and 'each work unit must cut its use of energy by 20% of current levels by 2010.' The plan fails to mention raising the price of electricity and gasoline, and unlike the previous 10 years, sets no economic growth targets.
In Part Two, Prof. Haley covers how profitable and available those subsidies are and how profitable companies are that serve the China market.
(The entire U.S.-China Commission hearing record for April 4, 2006 is available at www.uscc.gov/hearings/2006hearings/transcripts/april_4/06_04_04_trans.pdf.)
With each successive large-scale cyber attack, it is slowly becoming clear that ransomware attacks are targeting the critical infrastructure of the most powerful country on the planet. Understanding the strategy, and tactics of our opponents, as well as the strategy and the tactics we implement as a response are vital to victory.
This article highlights how copyright law in the United Kingdom differs from U.S. copyright law, and points out differences that may be crucial to entertainment and media businesses familiar with U.S law that are interested in operating in the United Kingdom or under UK law. The article also briefly addresses contrasts in UK and U.S. trademark law.
In June 2024, the First Department decided Huguenot LLC v. Megalith Capital Group Fund I, L.P., which resolved a question of liability for a group of condominium apartment buyers and in so doing, touched on a wide range of issues about how contracts can obligate purchasers of real property.
The Article 8 opt-in election adds an additional layer of complexity to the already labyrinthine rules governing perfection of security interests under the UCC. A lender that is unaware of the nuances created by the opt in (may find its security interest vulnerable to being primed by another party that has taken steps to perfect in a superior manner under the circumstances.