Law.com Subscribers SAVE 30%

Call 855-808-4530 or email [email protected] to receive your discount on a new subscription.

On the Modern American Class Action

By David L. Wallace and Michael R. Kelly
September 02, 2015

In Shakespeare's Henry VI, Part 2, rebel leader Jack Cade, a pretender to the throne, boldly declares a utopian vision for his kingdom-to-be.

There shall be in England seven half-penny loaves sold for a penny: the three-hoop'd pot shall have ten hoops; and I will make it felony to drink small beer: all the realm shall be in common, he says.

God save your majesty! his gang shouts in unison.

When I am king, Jack continues, there shall be no money; all shall eat and drink on my score; and I will apparel them all in one livery, that they may agree like brothers, and worship me their lord.

One of Jack's henchmen, Dick the Butcher, then utters the famous line: The first thing we do, let's kill all the lawyers.

Scholars ever since have debated the meaning of Dick's proposal: whether he meant to praise lawyers as the guardians of social order, or to suggest instead that their elimination might restore sanity to commercial life. As a defense lawyer, I lean to the latter view in the belief that Shakespeare probably had a nagging premonition about the havoc wreaked by the use of rule 23(b)(3) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure.

In the interest of self-preservation, however, along with the restoration of sanity to commercial life, rather than “all the lawyers,” I think we should kill the damage class action. The many food, beverage and drink companies being forced to defend their product labeling against scarcely credible allegations of consumer deception ' in a continually proliferating web of large proposed damage class actions (centered chiefly in California federal courts) ' might agree. So, I say, “The first thing we do, let's kill rule 23(b)(3).”

This article examines this proposal ' from a defense attorney's perspective ' using as an example the present scourge of food litigation being driven by class-action attorneys on the dubious theory that a regulatory violation of any magnitude amounts to an unfair or deceptive trade practice under state consumer protection statutes. It concludes by endorsing recommendations that rule 23 be scaled back and limited to injunctive relief class actions only, which was its original purpose.

The Golden Age of Public-Interest Lawyers

In a compelling anatomy of the state of the modern American class action, Professor Linda Mullenix explains that this unique procedural mechanism emerged in the mid-1960s, “during a period of celebrated liberal legislative initiatives intended to expand the civil rights and liberties of ordinary American citizens” ' the hallmark of President Lyndon Johnson's “Great Society legislative program.” Linda S. Mullenix, Ending Class Actions As We Know Them: Rethinking the American Class Action, 64 Emory L. J. 399, 401 (2014). These new substantive rights, however, served little purpose without a means for enforcing them. So, in tandem with Congress' massive reordering of civil society, the Advisory Committee on Civil Rules “embarked on a contemporaneous initiative to liberalize” rule 23 of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure. Id. Its resulting 1966 amendment generally cut class actions loose from the early constrictions and ambiguities of equity, helping to facilitate major social justice reforms in the late 1960s and early 1970s. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 23, advisory committee's note (1966); see also Benjamin Kaplan, 1966 Amendments of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, 81 Harv. L. Rev. 356, 380 (1967) (“In the wash of more than a quarter-century's experience, rule 23 did not come out very well.”).

This was the “so-called golden age of class litigation,” when public interest lawyers used rule 23's new “class action mechanism to integrate school systems, deinstitutionalize mental health facilities, reform conditions of confinement for inmates in prison systems, challenge discriminatory housing and public accommodation laws, and address various types of employment discrimination.” Id. at 402. The distinguishing feature of these landmark cases is that the lawyers and representative plaintiffs behind them sought only injunctive relief ' notwithstanding the availability of damage class actions courtesy of the 1966 amendments. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(b)(3). The lawyers who mounted these cases were motivated by genuine altruism, not money.

The Evolution of Mass Tort Class Actions: The Dark Ages

By the late 1970s, the proverbial bloom was off the class-action rose. Mass torts driven by less altruistic lawyers seeking compensatory damages and chunky fee awards under rule 23(b)(3) quickly replaced institutional reform litigation “as the new paradigmatic complex litigation.” Id. at 403. Over the course of the next 20 years, class-action litigation became big business, with enterprising plaintiff's attorneys flooding state and federal courts with all manner of mass-tort class actions. By the late 1990s, this litigation had been pushed almost entirely into the closet of the state courts by a series of restrictive federal appellate and Supreme Court decisions, where it remained “until Congress enacted the Class Action Fairness Act of 2005.” Id. & n.12 (collecting cases that briefly ended federal mass tort class litigation pre-CAFA).

With deceptive advertising claims now dominating the 21st-century landscape, the modern American class action has traced an arc “from the golden age of class litigation during the 1960s” to the Dark Age. Id. at 404. For instance, rather than deciding not to continue to purchase food products that do not meet their expectations or claimed preferences, because the food is not “natural” or “fresh” or “pure” enough for them, nominal plaintiffs are instead seeking millions of dollars in restitution or disgorgement in rule 23(b)(3) damage class actions ' alleging violations of consumer protection statutes. Frequently, however, the representative plaintiffs lending their names to these suits are simply pawns in a game being played by a group of enterprising lawyers looking for their next big payday. See id. at 416 (describing class counsel “as entrepreneurial bounty hunters stirring up faux class actions in the attorneys' own primary interest of recovering large fees”); Martin H. Redish, Wholesale Justice: Constitutional Democracy and the Problem of the Class Action Lawsuit 24-35 (2009) (voicing concern about the “faux” class action from a systemic perspective).

The upshot is that the modern American class action is “a fundamentally new and different procedural animal” with “its own unique procedural DNA;” and the most disconcerting aspect of it is that “[t]he nature of the relationship between clients and attorneys ' is like no form of litigation our system has ever seen,” nothing remotely like the traditional attorney-client relationship. Martin H. Redish, Rethinking the Theory of the Class Action: The Risks and Rewards of Capitalistic Socialism in the Litigation Process, 64 Emory L. J. 451, 454 (2014).

For those on the sharp end of this stick ' courts, defendants, and consumers who ultimately foot the bill for the lawsuits (in the form of increased costs) ' this is an intolerable state of affairs. “While a just society must always protect its genuine imbeciles, courts must not let the law be gamed by those merely posing as imbeciles in order to steal from others.” Am. Tort Reform Found, Food Class Actions by “Fake Imbeciles” Seek to Mislead, Manipulate Courts, Judicial Hellholes (Sept. 4, 2012). That is exactly what is going on, however, and the damage class action is the fulcrum.

Rethinking the Modern American Damage Class Action

The modern-day pretenders to the throne of the golden age of the American class action cast themselves as “white knights” or “beknighted 'private attorneys general' stepping into the breach of public regulatory enforcement, pursuing and vindicating justice where governmental enforcement is feeble or lacking.” Mullenix, supra, at 411. And “with scant empirical proof,” they claim to be promoting compensation, deterrence, and judicial efficiency. The truth is anything but that.

The Myths

1. Compensation. Like others before them, the attorneys responsible for the tsunami of food litigation now flooding court dockets across the country have “conceive[d] the tort, advertise[d] it to the public, and [found] ' clients to pursue the claims.” Id. at 414, quoting Kelly Brilleaux & Stephen G.A. Myers, Reevaluating the 401/403 Balance in Twenty-First Century Mass Torts, For Def. 48 (Feb. 2014). See also S. Storm, Lawyers from Suits Against Big Tobacco Target Food Makers, N.Y. Times (Aug. 18, 2012) (quoting a lawyer leading a recent surge in food litigation to effect that he and his partner firms targeted food and beverage makers after “research[ing] regulations and product labels for two years”). In the big picture, they are not helping anyone but themselves.

Further, the little evidence available on participation rates in class-action litigation settlements shows that very few claims are ultimately filed with settlement administrators. The settlement approved In re Heartland Payment Sys., Inc. Customer Data Sec. Breach Litig., 851 F.Supp.2d 1040, 1050 (S.D. Tex. 2012), is illustrative. It provided a “minimal recovery for Plaintiffs” and “was noteworthy mostly for the fact that one member of the class objected that the settlement was unfair to the Defendant because most of the class members were not harmed, an assertion borne out by the extraordinarily low claim rate of eleven total from a class of over 100 million.” Stephanie M. Lantagne, A Matter of National Importance: The Persistent Inefficiency of Deceptive Advertising Claims, 8 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 117, 133-34 (2013) (emphasis in original). And we have no reason to believe that the claim rate in food litigation is any different in this respect.

More likely than not, the vast majority of class members have no notion of harm in the circumstances, or (if so) consider it too minor to be worth the bother, or simply are not the type to pursue class-action litigation as a trivial pursuit in life. Mullenix, supra, at 413. Here, again, the lawyers driving these cases are helping only themselves, because their fees are generally fixed as a percentage of the settlement fund, not the actual claim rate. They are also often aiding allied interests to the extent unclaimed settlement funds not returned to defendants are distributed to various public-interest groups as cy-pres awards.

2. Deterrence. While no company wishes to find itself in the eye of a class action, most simply reckon the beast a cost of doing business today, with the cost covered by insurance companies or passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices. Cheap settlements with no admission of liability further minimize the claimed deterrence value of class litigation, and cases not certified obviously deter nothing: “In sum, nuisance-value class suits that are quickly compromised at discount rates,” which fairly describes the few food class-action settlements publicized to date, “are unlikely to serve any deterrent function.” Id. at 421. Take for instance the case of Mirabella v. Vital Pharmaceuticals, Inc., a putative class action alleging that an energy drink maker hid dangerous side effects of its products from consumers. The parties eventually settled the named plaintiffs' claims for about the cost of one drink each. Mirabella , No. 12-62086 (S.D. Fla. Mar. 16, 2015). As with the compensation function, arguments for “the deterrent effect of class litigation are largely theoretical, conclusory pronouncements.” Mullenix, supra, at 420. Still, they are repeated with “religious-like” fervor. Id. at 440.

3. Judicial Efficiency and Economy. Finally, the bundling of claims under rule 23(b)(3) is said to promote both judicial efficiency (by relieving docket congestion), and the speedy resolution of multiple claims in one proceeding. But tell that to California federal judges sitting in the Central and Northern Districts (the nation's “food court”), whose dockets are loaded with food class actions; or to food companies facing duplicative cases characterized by the serial amendment of class-action complaints in the face of dispositive motions practice ' followed by expensive class discovery, certification briefing, related hearings, seemingly endless motions for reconsideration, further dispositive motions, and, quite often, appeals. Here, again, empirical evidence is lacking to support the assertion that class action litigation is more efficient than traditional litigation. Id. at 423.

Lawyers, Food and Money

Food litigation grounded on deceptive and misleading labeling claims is just the latest example. Motivated by the prospect of large fee awards ' commonly enhanced by the availability of trebled damages, punitive damages, and attorneys' fees under many consumer protection statutes ' plaintiffs' attorneys gather their clients into courthouses across the country, alleging that their clients (and thousands, sometimes millions, of supposedly hapless and helpless folks just like them) were hoodwinked into purchasing grocery items that were either not “natural” enough for them, or mislabeled in some other hyper-technical manner that plaintiffs may never be able to articulate in deposition. The class-action vehicle, in turn, is said to be the superior means of resolving these claims because they are otherwise hardly worth the bother, given the high cost of litigation. The problem is that “everyone involved is incentivized to act against the best interests of the people for whom the system was designed to help ' consumers and the general public.” Id. The class-action, in short, “functions as a second rip-off of the consumer.” Lawrence W. Schonbrun, The Class Action Racket, Am. Thinker 2 (Apr. 1, 2013).

All things considered, a good case can be made that rule 23 damage class actions render rule 1 a dead letter. With rare exception, there is simply nothing “just, speedy, and inexpensive” about them. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 1. Any good the odd damage class action might do arguably comes at tremendous systemic cost, chiefly in terms of the typically spurious litigation it breeds. Rule 23 should be killed. “[S]even half-penny loaves” cannot be “sold for a penny,” “the three hoop'd pot” cannot “have ten hoops,” and modern class-action plaintiffs' lawyers are no more worthy of “worship” than was Jack Cade.

The Fix: Kill the Damage Class Action

Much like what was said of original rule 23, the advisory committee's invention of damage class actions in 1966 has not come out very well in the wash of more than half a century. As Judge William Young observed in the context of a data breach class action he oversaw several years ago: “Simply put, the class action vehicle is broken.” See In Re TJX Cos. Retail Sec. Breach Litig., No. 07-10162 (D. Mass. Nov. 3, 2008). And the damage class action, which has grown to “dominate the litigation landscape,” is the problem. Mullenix, supra , at 439. In hindsight, the addition of rule 23(b)(3) looks more like a lawyer's relief act than it does a measure intended “to ensure the participation of the poor and disadvantaged” in civil society. Schonbrun, supra, at 2.

A practical solution would be to leave enforcement of consumer protection statutes to regulatory authorities and other public officials, such as state attorneys general, who tend (for various reasons) to be much more circumspect in the exercise of their enforcement powers than private attorneys (motivated by extraneous factors). With the National Association of Attorneys General now routinely flexing its muscle, extracting large cash settlements and voluntary injunctions from companies and entire industries for allegedly unfair and deceptive trade practices, the original justification for deputizing “beknighted 'private attorneys general'” to do the job ' the enfeebled regulatory state ' seems questionable. Allowed the luxury of an unfettered discretion not available to public officials, private lawyers have time and time again demonstrated a propensity to invest it in class actions that end up making “the little injuries of life” considerably larger with simple multiplication (of claims) and addition (of their fees). Id. at 3.

As a scarred veteran of the class-action battleground, I believe that the observations of Mullenix and others are exactly right. Eliminate the damage class action, which seems to “exist[ ] primarily to remunerate (and reward) entrepreneurial attorneys with outsized fee awards,” and “return the class action to its primary function in the 1960s: the injunctive relief class only.” Mullenix, supra, at 440. Leave it to regulators to deal with corporate behavior that gives rise to the small-bore harms that generally characterize the modern class action ' through “penalties, fines, product recalls or withdrawals, or criminal sanctions.” Id. In response to those who might say that private attorneys general are needed to supplement perceived laxity in public enforcement of consumer protection laws, “the answer is ' not to promote a class action system with its own egregious problems but instead to advocate and labor for more robust regulatory oversight and enforcement systems.” Id.

Conclusion

Rather than “kill all the lawyers” to solve the plague of damage class actions, reformers should consider returning rule 23 to its roots by killing the (b)(3) category instead, which has proved to be the source of altogether too much mischief. This one act would arguably go a long way to restoring sanity to commercial life and clearing the legal landscape of much dead wood.


David L. Wallace, a member of this newsletter's Board of Editors, is a partner in the New York office of Herbert Smith Freehills LLP. He has defended and counseled multinational corporations in an array of product-related disputes for more than 25 years. Michael R. Kelly is a senior associate in same office. He has over a decade of experience advising and defending consumer products manufacturers facing class action litigation in the United States and abroad. The opinions expressed in this article are the authors' own and do not necessarily reflect the views of their firm or clients.

In Shakespeare's Henry VI, Part 2, rebel leader Jack Cade, a pretender to the throne, boldly declares a utopian vision for his kingdom-to-be.

There shall be in England seven half-penny loaves sold for a penny: the three-hoop'd pot shall have ten hoops; and I will make it felony to drink small beer: all the realm shall be in common, he says.

God save your majesty! his gang shouts in unison.

When I am king, Jack continues, there shall be no money; all shall eat and drink on my score; and I will apparel them all in one livery, that they may agree like brothers, and worship me their lord.

One of Jack's henchmen, Dick the Butcher, then utters the famous line: The first thing we do, let's kill all the lawyers.

Scholars ever since have debated the meaning of Dick's proposal: whether he meant to praise lawyers as the guardians of social order, or to suggest instead that their elimination might restore sanity to commercial life. As a defense lawyer, I lean to the latter view in the belief that Shakespeare probably had a nagging premonition about the havoc wreaked by the use of rule 23(b)(3) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure.

In the interest of self-preservation, however, along with the restoration of sanity to commercial life, rather than “all the lawyers,” I think we should kill the damage class action. The many food, beverage and drink companies being forced to defend their product labeling against scarcely credible allegations of consumer deception ' in a continually proliferating web of large proposed damage class actions (centered chiefly in California federal courts) ' might agree. So, I say, “The first thing we do, let's kill rule 23(b)(3).”

This article examines this proposal ' from a defense attorney's perspective ' using as an example the present scourge of food litigation being driven by class-action attorneys on the dubious theory that a regulatory violation of any magnitude amounts to an unfair or deceptive trade practice under state consumer protection statutes. It concludes by endorsing recommendations that rule 23 be scaled back and limited to injunctive relief class actions only, which was its original purpose.

The Golden Age of Public-Interest Lawyers

In a compelling anatomy of the state of the modern American class action, Professor Linda Mullenix explains that this unique procedural mechanism emerged in the mid-1960s, “during a period of celebrated liberal legislative initiatives intended to expand the civil rights and liberties of ordinary American citizens” ' the hallmark of President Lyndon Johnson's “Great Society legislative program.” Linda S. Mullenix, Ending Class Actions As We Know Them: Rethinking the American Class Action, 64 Emory L. J. 399, 401 (2014). These new substantive rights, however, served little purpose without a means for enforcing them. So, in tandem with Congress' massive reordering of civil society, the Advisory Committee on Civil Rules “embarked on a contemporaneous initiative to liberalize” rule 23 of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure. Id. Its resulting 1966 amendment generally cut class actions loose from the early constrictions and ambiguities of equity, helping to facilitate major social justice reforms in the late 1960s and early 1970s. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 23, advisory committee's note (1966); see also Benjamin Kaplan, 1966 Amendments of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, 81 Harv. L. Rev. 356, 380 (1967) (“In the wash of more than a quarter-century's experience, rule 23 did not come out very well.”).

This was the “so-called golden age of class litigation,” when public interest lawyers used rule 23's new “class action mechanism to integrate school systems, deinstitutionalize mental health facilities, reform conditions of confinement for inmates in prison systems, challenge discriminatory housing and public accommodation laws, and address various types of employment discrimination.” Id. at 402. The distinguishing feature of these landmark cases is that the lawyers and representative plaintiffs behind them sought only injunctive relief ' notwithstanding the availability of damage class actions courtesy of the 1966 amendments. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(b)(3). The lawyers who mounted these cases were motivated by genuine altruism, not money.

The Evolution of Mass Tort Class Actions: The Dark Ages

By the late 1970s, the proverbial bloom was off the class-action rose. Mass torts driven by less altruistic lawyers seeking compensatory damages and chunky fee awards under rule 23(b)(3) quickly replaced institutional reform litigation “as the new paradigmatic complex litigation.” Id. at 403. Over the course of the next 20 years, class-action litigation became big business, with enterprising plaintiff's attorneys flooding state and federal courts with all manner of mass-tort class actions. By the late 1990s, this litigation had been pushed almost entirely into the closet of the state courts by a series of restrictive federal appellate and Supreme Court decisions, where it remained “until Congress enacted the Class Action Fairness Act of 2005.” Id. & n.12 (collecting cases that briefly ended federal mass tort class litigation pre-CAFA).

With deceptive advertising claims now dominating the 21st-century landscape, the modern American class action has traced an arc “from the golden age of class litigation during the 1960s” to the Dark Age. Id. at 404. For instance, rather than deciding not to continue to purchase food products that do not meet their expectations or claimed preferences, because the food is not “natural” or “fresh” or “pure” enough for them, nominal plaintiffs are instead seeking millions of dollars in restitution or disgorgement in rule 23(b)(3) damage class actions ' alleging violations of consumer protection statutes. Frequently, however, the representative plaintiffs lending their names to these suits are simply pawns in a game being played by a group of enterprising lawyers looking for their next big payday. See id. at 416 (describing class counsel “as entrepreneurial bounty hunters stirring up faux class actions in the attorneys' own primary interest of recovering large fees”); Martin H. Redish, Wholesale Justice: Constitutional Democracy and the Problem of the Class Action Lawsuit 24-35 (2009) (voicing concern about the “faux” class action from a systemic perspective).

The upshot is that the modern American class action is “a fundamentally new and different procedural animal” with “its own unique procedural DNA;” and the most disconcerting aspect of it is that “[t]he nature of the relationship between clients and attorneys ' is like no form of litigation our system has ever seen,” nothing remotely like the traditional attorney-client relationship. Martin H. Redish, Rethinking the Theory of the Class Action: The Risks and Rewards of Capitalistic Socialism in the Litigation Process, 64 Emory L. J. 451, 454 (2014).

For those on the sharp end of this stick ' courts, defendants, and consumers who ultimately foot the bill for the lawsuits (in the form of increased costs) ' this is an intolerable state of affairs. “While a just society must always protect its genuine imbeciles, courts must not let the law be gamed by those merely posing as imbeciles in order to steal from others.” Am. Tort Reform Found, Food Class Actions by “Fake Imbeciles” Seek to Mislead, Manipulate Courts, Judicial Hellholes (Sept. 4, 2012). That is exactly what is going on, however, and the damage class action is the fulcrum.

Rethinking the Modern American Damage Class Action

The modern-day pretenders to the throne of the golden age of the American class action cast themselves as “white knights” or “beknighted 'private attorneys general' stepping into the breach of public regulatory enforcement, pursuing and vindicating justice where governmental enforcement is feeble or lacking.” Mullenix, supra, at 411. And “with scant empirical proof,” they claim to be promoting compensation, deterrence, and judicial efficiency. The truth is anything but that.

The Myths

1. Compensation. Like others before them, the attorneys responsible for the tsunami of food litigation now flooding court dockets across the country have “conceive[d] the tort, advertise[d] it to the public, and [found] ' clients to pursue the claims.” Id. at 414, quoting Kelly Brilleaux & Stephen G.A. Myers, Reevaluating the 401/403 Balance in Twenty-First Century Mass Torts, For Def. 48 (Feb. 2014). See also S. Storm, Lawyers from Suits Against Big Tobacco Target Food Makers, N.Y. Times (Aug. 18, 2012) (quoting a lawyer leading a recent surge in food litigation to effect that he and his partner firms targeted food and beverage makers after “research[ing] regulations and product labels for two years”). In the big picture, they are not helping anyone but themselves.

Further, the little evidence available on participation rates in class-action litigation settlements shows that very few claims are ultimately filed with settlement administrators. The settlement approved In re Heartland Payment Sys., Inc. Customer Data Sec. Breach Litig., 851 F.Supp.2d 1040, 1050 (S.D. Tex. 2012), is illustrative. It provided a “minimal recovery for Plaintiffs” and “was noteworthy mostly for the fact that one member of the class objected that the settlement was unfair to the Defendant because most of the class members were not harmed, an assertion borne out by the extraordinarily low claim rate of eleven total from a class of over 100 million.” Stephanie M. Lantagne, A Matter of National Importance: The Persistent Inefficiency of Deceptive Advertising Claims, 8 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 117, 133-34 (2013) (emphasis in original). And we have no reason to believe that the claim rate in food litigation is any different in this respect.

More likely than not, the vast majority of class members have no notion of harm in the circumstances, or (if so) consider it too minor to be worth the bother, or simply are not the type to pursue class-action litigation as a trivial pursuit in life. Mullenix, supra, at 413. Here, again, the lawyers driving these cases are helping only themselves, because their fees are generally fixed as a percentage of the settlement fund, not the actual claim rate. They are also often aiding allied interests to the extent unclaimed settlement funds not returned to defendants are distributed to various public-interest groups as cy-pres awards.

2. Deterrence. While no company wishes to find itself in the eye of a class action, most simply reckon the beast a cost of doing business today, with the cost covered by insurance companies or passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices. Cheap settlements with no admission of liability further minimize the claimed deterrence value of class litigation, and cases not certified obviously deter nothing: “In sum, nuisance-value class suits that are quickly compromised at discount rates,” which fairly describes the few food class-action settlements publicized to date, “are unlikely to serve any deterrent function.” Id. at 421. Take for instance the case of Mirabella v. Vital Pharmaceuticals, Inc., a putative class action alleging that an energy drink maker hid dangerous side effects of its products from consumers. The parties eventually settled the named plaintiffs' claims for about the cost of one drink each. Mirabella , No. 12-62086 (S.D. Fla. Mar. 16, 2015). As with the compensation function, arguments for “the deterrent effect of class litigation are largely theoretical, conclusory pronouncements.” Mullenix, supra, at 420. Still, they are repeated with “religious-like” fervor. Id. at 440.

3. Judicial Efficiency and Economy. Finally, the bundling of claims under rule 23(b)(3) is said to promote both judicial efficiency (by relieving docket congestion), and the speedy resolution of multiple claims in one proceeding. But tell that to California federal judges sitting in the Central and Northern Districts (the nation's “food court”), whose dockets are loaded with food class actions; or to food companies facing duplicative cases characterized by the serial amendment of class-action complaints in the face of dispositive motions practice ' followed by expensive class discovery, certification briefing, related hearings, seemingly endless motions for reconsideration, further dispositive motions, and, quite often, appeals. Here, again, empirical evidence is lacking to support the assertion that class action litigation is more efficient than traditional litigation. Id. at 423.

Lawyers, Food and Money

Food litigation grounded on deceptive and misleading labeling claims is just the latest example. Motivated by the prospect of large fee awards ' commonly enhanced by the availability of trebled damages, punitive damages, and attorneys' fees under many consumer protection statutes ' plaintiffs' attorneys gather their clients into courthouses across the country, alleging that their clients (and thousands, sometimes millions, of supposedly hapless and helpless folks just like them) were hoodwinked into purchasing grocery items that were either not “natural” enough for them, or mislabeled in some other hyper-technical manner that plaintiffs may never be able to articulate in deposition. The class-action vehicle, in turn, is said to be the superior means of resolving these claims because they are otherwise hardly worth the bother, given the high cost of litigation. The problem is that “everyone involved is incentivized to act against the best interests of the people for whom the system was designed to help ' consumers and the general public.” Id. The class-action, in short, “functions as a second rip-off of the consumer.” Lawrence W. Schonbrun, The Class Action Racket, Am. Thinker 2 (Apr. 1, 2013).

All things considered, a good case can be made that rule 23 damage class actions render rule 1 a dead letter. With rare exception, there is simply nothing “just, speedy, and inexpensive” about them. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 1. Any good the odd damage class action might do arguably comes at tremendous systemic cost, chiefly in terms of the typically spurious litigation it breeds. Rule 23 should be killed. “[S]even half-penny loaves” cannot be “sold for a penny,” “the three hoop'd pot” cannot “have ten hoops,” and modern class-action plaintiffs' lawyers are no more worthy of “worship” than was Jack Cade.

The Fix: Kill the Damage Class Action

Much like what was said of original rule 23, the advisory committee's invention of damage class actions in 1966 has not come out very well in the wash of more than half a century. As Judge William Young observed in the context of a data breach class action he oversaw several years ago: “Simply put, the class action vehicle is broken.” See In Re TJX Cos. Retail Sec. Breach Litig., No. 07-10162 (D. Mass. Nov. 3, 2008). And the damage class action, which has grown to “dominate the litigation landscape,” is the problem. Mullenix, supra , at 439. In hindsight, the addition of rule 23(b)(3) looks more like a lawyer's relief act than it does a measure intended “to ensure the participation of the poor and disadvantaged” in civil society. Schonbrun, supra, at 2.

A practical solution would be to leave enforcement of consumer protection statutes to regulatory authorities and other public officials, such as state attorneys general, who tend (for various reasons) to be much more circumspect in the exercise of their enforcement powers than private attorneys (motivated by extraneous factors). With the National Association of Attorneys General now routinely flexing its muscle, extracting large cash settlements and voluntary injunctions from companies and entire industries for allegedly unfair and deceptive trade practices, the original justification for deputizing “beknighted 'private attorneys general'” to do the job ' the enfeebled regulatory state ' seems questionable. Allowed the luxury of an unfettered discretion not available to public officials, private lawyers have time and time again demonstrated a propensity to invest it in class actions that end up making “the little injuries of life” considerably larger with simple multiplication (of claims) and addition (of their fees). Id. at 3.

As a scarred veteran of the class-action battleground, I believe that the observations of Mullenix and others are exactly right. Eliminate the damage class action, which seems to “exist[ ] primarily to remunerate (and reward) entrepreneurial attorneys with outsized fee awards,” and “return the class action to its primary function in the 1960s: the injunctive relief class only.” Mullenix, supra, at 440. Leave it to regulators to deal with corporate behavior that gives rise to the small-bore harms that generally characterize the modern class action ' through “penalties, fines, product recalls or withdrawals, or criminal sanctions.” Id. In response to those who might say that private attorneys general are needed to supplement perceived laxity in public enforcement of consumer protection laws, “the answer is ' not to promote a class action system with its own egregious problems but instead to advocate and labor for more robust regulatory oversight and enforcement systems.” Id.

Conclusion

Rather than “kill all the lawyers” to solve the plague of damage class actions, reformers should consider returning rule 23 to its roots by killing the (b)(3) category instead, which has proved to be the source of altogether too much mischief. This one act would arguably go a long way to restoring sanity to commercial life and clearing the legal landscape of much dead wood.


David L. Wallace, a member of this newsletter's Board of Editors, is a partner in the New York office of Herbert Smith Freehills LLP. He has defended and counseled multinational corporations in an array of product-related disputes for more than 25 years. Michael R. Kelly is a senior associate in same office. He has over a decade of experience advising and defending consumer products manufacturers facing class action litigation in the United States and abroad. The opinions expressed in this article are the authors' own and do not necessarily reflect the views of their firm or clients.

This premium content is locked for Entertainment Law & Finance subscribers only

  • Stay current on the latest information, rulings, regulations, and trends
  • Includes practical, must-have information on copyrights, royalties, AI, and more
  • Tap into expert guidance from top entertainment lawyers and experts

For enterprise-wide or corporate acess, please contact Customer Service at [email protected] or 877-256-2473

Read These Next
Strategy vs. Tactics: Two Sides of a Difficult Coin Image

With each successive large-scale cyber attack, it is slowly becoming clear that ransomware attacks are targeting the critical infrastructure of the most powerful country on the planet. Understanding the strategy, and tactics of our opponents, as well as the strategy and the tactics we implement as a response are vital to victory.

'Huguenot LLC v. Megalith Capital Group Fund I, L.P.': A Tutorial On Contract Liability for Real Estate Purchasers Image

In June 2024, the First Department decided Huguenot LLC v. Megalith Capital Group Fund I, L.P., which resolved a question of liability for a group of condominium apartment buyers and in so doing, touched on a wide range of issues about how contracts can obligate purchasers of real property.

Fresh Filings Image

Notable recent court filings in entertainment law.

Major Differences In UK, U.S. Copyright Laws Image

This article highlights how copyright law in the United Kingdom differs from U.S. copyright law, and points out differences that may be crucial to entertainment and media businesses familiar with U.S law that are interested in operating in the United Kingdom or under UK law. The article also briefly addresses contrasts in UK and U.S. trademark law.

The Article 8 Opt In Image

The Article 8 opt-in election adds an additional layer of complexity to the already labyrinthine rules governing perfection of security interests under the UCC. A lender that is unaware of the nuances created by the opt in (may find its security interest vulnerable to being primed by another party that has taken steps to perfect in a superior manner under the circumstances.